The Model The CAPM was developed, at least in part, to explain the differences in risk premium across assets. According to the CAPM, these differences are due to differences in the riskiness of the returns on the assets. The model asserts that the correct measure of riskiness is its measure--known as beta--and that the risk premium per unit of riskiness is the same across all assets. Given the risk-free rate and the beta of an asset, the CAPM predicts the expected risk premium for that asset. In this section, we will derive a version of the CAPM. In the next section, we will examine whether the CAPM is actually consistent with the average rerum differences. To derive the CAPM, we start with the simple problem of choosing a portfolio of assets for an arbitrarily chosen investor. To set up the problem, we need a few definitions. Let R0 be the return (that is, one plus the rate of return) on the risk-free asset (asset 0). By investing $1, the investor will get $R0 for sure. In addition, assume that the number of risky assets is n. The risky assets have returns that are not known with certainty at the time the investments are made. Let alphai be the fraction of the investor's initial wealth that is allocated to asset i. Then Ri is the return on asset i. Let Rm be the return on the entire portfolio (that is, sigman, sub i=0) alphai Ri). Here Ri is a random variable with expected value ERi and variance var(Ri), where variance is a measure of the volatility of the return. The covariance between the return of asset i and the return of asset j is represented by cov(Ri, Rj). Covariance provides a measure of how the returns on the two assets, i and j, move together. Suppose that the investor's expected utility can be represented as a function of the expected return on the investor's portfolio and its variance. In order to simplify notation without losing generality, assume that the investor can choose to allocate wealth to three assets: i = 0, 1, or 2. Then the problem is to choose fractions alpha0, alpha1, and alpha2 that maximize (1) V(ERm,var(Rm))) subject to (2) alpha0 + alpha1 + alpha2 = 1 (3) ERm = alpha0R0 + alpha1ER1 + alpha2ER2 (4) var (Rm) = alpha2, sub 1 var (R1) + alpha2, sub 2 var (R2) + 2 alpha1 alpha2 cov (R1, R2. The objective function V is increasing in the expected return, deltaV/deltaERmm > 0; decreasing in thee variance of the return deltaV/delta var(R[sub m) < 0; and concave. These properties imply that there is a trade-off between expected returns and the variance of returns. The constraint n equation (2) ensures that the fractions sum to 1. Equations (3) and (4) follow from the definition of the rate of return on the wealth portfolio of the investor, Rm. Substituting 1 - alpha1 - alpha2 for alpha0 in equation (1) and taking the derivative of V with respect to alpha1 and alpha2 yields the following conditions that must hold at an optimum: (5) (ER1 - R0) V1 + 2[alpha1 var(R1) + alpha2 cov (R1, R2) V2 = 0 (6) (ER1 - R0) V1 + 2[alpha2 var(R1) + alpha2 cov (R1, R2) V2 = 0 where Vj is thee partial derivative of V with respect to its jth argument, for j = 1, 2. Now consider multiplying equation (5) by alpha1 and equation (6) by alpha2 and summing the results: (7) [alpha1 (ER1 - R0 + alpha2 (ER2 -R0) V1 + 2 {alpha1 var (R1) + alpha2 cov (R1, R2) + alpha2 [alpha2 var (R2 + alpha1 cov (R1, R[sub 2)]} V2 = 0 Using the definitions of ERmmm and var(Rm), we can write this more succinctly: (8) (ERm - R0 V1 + 2var (Rm) V2 = 0. The expressions in (5), (6), and (8) can all be written as explicit functions of the ratio V2/V1, and then the first two expressions [from (5) and (6)] can be equated to the third [from (8)]. This yields the following two relationships: (9) ERi - R0 = [cov(Rj, Rm)var(Rm)](ERm- R0) for i = 1, 2. In fact, even for the more general case, where n is not necessarily equal to 2, equation (9) holds. Let cov(Ri, Rm)/var(Rm) be the beta of asset i, or betai. Then we have (10) ER1 = R0 + (ERm - R0) Betai for all i = 1, . . . , n. A portfolio is said to be on the mean-variance frontier of the return/variance relationship if no other choice of weights alpha0, alphaj (for j = 1, 2, . . . , n) yields a lower variance for the same expected return. The portfolio is said to be on the efficient part of the frontier if, in addition, no other portfolio has a higher expected rerum. The optimally chosen portfolio for the problem in equations (1)-(4) has this property. In fact, equation (10) will continue to hold if the return Rm is replaced by the return on any mean-variance efficient portfolio other than the risk-free asset. Note that the return Rm in (10) is the return for one investor's wealth portfolio. But equation (10) holds for every mean-variance efficient portfolio, and V need not be the same for all investors. A property of mean-variance efficient portfolios is that portfolios of them are also mean-variance efficient. If we define the market portfolio to be a weighted sum of individual portfolios with the weights determined by the fractions of total wealth held by individuals, then the market portfolio is mean-variance efficient too. Therefore, an equation of the form given by (10) also holds for the market portfolio. In fact, equation (10) with Rm equal to the return on the market portfolio is the key relation for the CAPM. This relation implies that all assets i have the same ratios of reward, measured as the expected return in excess of the risk-free rate (ERi - R0), to risk (betai). This is consistent with the notion that investors trade off return and risk. In specifying the problem of a typical investor [in (1)-(4)], we assumed that a risk-free asset is available. If we drop this assumption and set alpha0 = 0 from the start, then we obtain a slightly different relationship between return and risk than is given in (10). In particular, Black (1993) shows that without a risk-free asset, expected returns on the risky assets satisfy this relationship: (11) ER1 = ERz + (ERm - Rz)Betai where Rz is the return on a zero-beta portfolio [that is, cov(RzRm = 0], Rm is the return on the market portfolio, and betai = cov (rj, Rm/var (Rm). We now provide an interpretation of beta in (10) or (11) as a measure of the asset's contribution to portfolio risk. Consider a portfolio p of assets that earns return Rp and has standard deviation Sp = (var Rp)1/2. Let the standard deviation of an arbitrary asset i be Si and the covariance between asset i's return and that of the portfolio be Ci,p. Now consider a new portfolio with xi invested in asset i, -xi invested in the risk-free asset, and xp invested in the original portfolio. That is, consider modifying the portfolio of an investor who currently holds xp in portfolio p by borrowing $xi and investing it in asset i. The standard deviation of the new portfolio is then (12) S = (x2, sub i S2, sub i + x2, sub p S2, sub p + 2xi xp Ci, p)1/2. |